Negative Externality

Negative Externality

A negative externality occurs when an individual or firm making a decision does not have to pay the full cost of the decision. If a good has a negative externality, then the cost to society is greater than the cost consumer is paying for it. Since consumers make a decision based on where their marginal cost equals their marginal benefit, and since they don't take into account the cost of the negative externality, negative externalities result in market inefficiencies unless proper action is taken.

When a negative externality exists in an unregulated market, producers don't take responsibility for external costs that exist--these are passed on to society. Thus producers have lower marginal costs than they would otherwise have and the supply curve is effectively shifted down (to the right) of the supply curve that society faces. Because the supply curve is increased, more of the product is bought than the efficient amount--that is, too much of the product is produced and sold. Since marginal benefit is not equal to marginal cost, a deadweight welfare loss results.

Graph of a negative externality This graph shows the effect of a negative externality. The red line represents society's supply curve/marginal cost curve while the black line represents the marginal cost curve that the firm or industry with the negative externality faces. The optimal production quantity is Q', but the negative externality results in production of Q*. The deadweight welfare loss is shown in gray.

A common example of a negative externality is pollution. For example, a steel producing firm might pump pollutants into the air. While the firm has to pay for electricity, materials, etc., the individuals living around the factory will pay for the pollution since it will cause them to have higher medical expenses, poorer quality of life, reduced aestetic appeal of the air, etc. Thus the production of steel by the firm has a negative cost to the people surrounding the factory--a cost that the steel firm doesn't have to pay.

There are still many other examples of negative externalities. These can include decisions that result in costs to other individuals: sitting on the end of a row so that others have to climb over you, littering, painting your house an ugly color in a nice neighborhood, not showering, cutting in line, etc.

Solving the Negative Externality Problem

Negative externalities are a property rights problem. Who owns the air that the steel mill pollutes? Ronald Coase put forth the solution which is known as the Coase Theorem:
"Under perfect competition, once government has assigned clearly defined property rights in contested resouces and as lon as transactions costs are negligible, private parties that generate or are affected by externalities will negotiate voluntary agreements that lead to the socially optimal resource allocation and output mix regardless of how the property rights are assigned" (Ronald H. Coase, "The Problem of Social Cost," The Journal of Law and Economics, October 1960).
In other words, if there are negligible transactions costs, as long as someone owns the rights to the air around the steel mill, the efficient outcome will prevail. For example, if the steel mill owns the rights, then the individuals that live around the mill will be willing to pay the steel mill not to produce--up to the cost that they are incurring from health care, reduced aesthetic appeal of the air, etc. This amount that they are willing to pay becomes an opportunity cost for the steel mill if they produce. Thus they will cut production to the optimal level. On the other hand, if the people own the air, then the steel mill would have to pay them that same amount for the right to produce. Thus the negative externality is directly added to the steel mill's marginal cost.

Another way to solve the negative externality problem is to simply tax the producer the amount of the negative externality. This adds to the producers marginal cost and will cause them to reduce output.

The video below discusses how taxes can discourage certain behavior.

Home
Accounting
Economics
Economics Articles
Economic Data
Economics Glossary
Macroeconomics
Economic Indicators
Fiscal Policy
Microeconomics
Comparative Advantage
The Supply Curve
Price Elasticity
Fixed & Variable Cost
ATC & Marginal Cost
Marginal Revenue
Output Decision
Price Floor
Price Ceiling
Negative Externalities
Positive Externalities
Price Gouging
Sunk Costs
Game Theory
Game Theory Introduction
Nash Equilibrium
Extensive Form
Monopolies
Monopolies
The Sherman Act
The Clayton Act
Papers
Bootstrap Method
The CAPM Model
Euro Creation and Crisis
FX and Inflation in Pakistan
Poverty and Crime
General Finance
Mergers / Acquisitions
Money Market
Options
Real Estate
Retirement
Stocks
Other Personal Finance
Opinions / Essays
Excel
Links


Share



Contact Us

Site Map

Disclaimer